Public Participation and Hearings in the New Thai Political Context(James R. Klein)
Public Participation and Hearings in the New Thai Political Context
Public Participation and Hearings in the New Thai
Political Context
James R. Klein1
Introduction
At the heart of
Thailand's 1997 Constitution is a revolutionary new scope for public participation.
First, it removes State control over the appointment of an Upper House
dominated by civil and military bureaucrats in favor of directly elected
Senators representing civil society. As a result of this reform, the bureaucracy
will no longer be able to exercise a veto over decisions made by MPs in the lower house. At the same
time, however, MPs will be held accountable to civil society for their decisions in
the lower house. Second, the constitution eliminates the bureaucracy's monopoly over
public policy
formulation in favor of public participation. Theoretically, bureaucrats will
no longer be able to develop and implement projects which serve bureaucratic
rather than public interests. Citizen concerns and interests will have to be
calculated into public policy decisions. Third, reforms erase the fiction of
bureaucratic ownership of national resources in favor of citizen stewardship. No
longer will bureaucrats determine how a community's resources are developed.
Citizens will have the right
to determine the status of their local environment. Fourth, the constitution establishes a process to diminish the central bureaucracy's domination over local affairs in
favor of political, fiscal, and
administrative decentralization. Theoretically, this means Bangkok-based agencies will no longer be able to
impose their will on
1 Dr. James R. Klein is the Thailand Country
Representative of The Asia Foundation. The
views expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily represent
those of The Asia Foundation. To learn more about The Asia Foundation visit their website at <www.asiafoundation.org>.
the course of local development. Individual
communities will develop at their own pace and in accordance with the wishes of
the majority.
These reforms, and
numerous other measures mandated by the constitution, were designed to promote
public participation. However, these reforms merely reflect constitutional theory; they
do not accurately
describe current Thai political realities. Before these theories can be
translated into reality, the nation must undergo a period of transition during which values,
attitudes, systems, and structures are
changed to support and uphold constitutional theory. This is because the interrelated constitutional
reforms are designed to dismantle Thailand's traditional form of
governance and replace it with a
participatory representative democracy.
Specifically, in
combination, all the reforms serve to:
1.Recast the
role of the bureaucracy from command and control to facilitation of public policy and the
efficient provision of public goods
and services; and,
2.Recast the role of citizens from passive subjugation to engaged participation
with access to redress.
There are those who
do not wish to see this transformation occur. Some of these individuals are
well-intended politicians, officials, and citizens who believe the majority of Thai
citizens lack the knowledge and skills to make their own decisions. Yet, others
simply do not wish to lose the power and wealth they have achieved under the traditional system. In the face
of resistance from these two groups, which remain influential and powerful, the
achievement of Thailand's constitutional reforms and this transformation in
governance will ultimately fail if citizens are unable to secure for themselves
the public participation rights granted by the 1997 Constitution.
Representative Governance vs Participatory
Representative Governance
Many democracies throughout
the world refer to themselves as democratically elected, representative
governments. Some of these nations
adhere to a representative form of governance, while others
could more accurately be referred to as
participatory representative governments. This is a distinction between two
forms of government that many Thai politicians, officials, and citizens fail
to recognize. It is important to highlight the distinction between these two systems of governance because
Thailand's 1997 constitutional reforms were designed to promote development of a
participatory representative government; the reforms were not intended simply to
repair or to preserve a representative government.
In its purest form, a
representative government is one in which citizens cast truly free and fair ballots on
a regularly scheduled basis to elect their representatives at various levels from
local to national. These elected officials set policies, as promised in their electoral campaign, and
implement these policies through the efforts of dedicated bureaucrats. If citizens
become displeased with the performance of their elected officials, citizens vote
them out of office at the next election.
Unfortunately,
representative governance (RG) is a Utopian ideal that has proven to
obscure many dangers to democracy. This is because it requires so many other ideals to
be absolutely true for it to function effectively as a system of good governance. RG
requires that all politicians, not just a few, be guided by public interest and
not self interest.
RG requires that all bureaucrats, not just a few, act as public servants rather
than proponents of their own agenda. And, ultimately, RG requires that all
elections be truly free and fair, where money politics and the abuse of power play
no role. Nations that adopt a representative government as their ideal eventually
experience a downward spiral toward widespread corruption, abuse of power, violation of civil
rights, and ultimately, the denial of citizens to freely and fairly elect their
representatives. Over time, unless significant reforms are undertaken, the ideal
representative government transforms itself into dictatorship by an elite.
The principal
democratic alternative to representative governance, and the best known remedy against
the problems inherent in representative governance, is participatory
representative governance (PRG). The fundamental distinctions between RG and
PRG are that PRG provides citizens with tools
to maintain constant oversight of their elected representatives, the
authority to effectively deter
officials from pursuing policies or projects opposed by the majority, and mechanisms to remove recalcitrant
officials from office without waiting
for the next election. PRG assumes that power corrupts and therefore not all elected leaders or bureaucrats will have
the best interests of the community in
mind. PRG assumes that powerful
individuals will abuse their power to win elections in order to pursue their own personal interests. PRG
assumes that it is the duty of citizens to protect their democratic
rights and promote good governance through
citizen participation.
Participatory
representative governance should not be confused with participatory governance (PG).
The latter is a system in which all stakeholders make a collective decision on
each, and every issue before
the community. While PG may be an admirable ideal of democracy, it simply is not a feasible option for managing a nation-state or even a local community. Representatives,
whose values and attitudes reflect those held by the majority of their
constituents, are essential to
adequately consider the complexities of the many decisions faced by modern communities. Under a PRG system, it is the role of a representative to govern on a daily
basis, and even to occasionally tell
their constituents bad news. For example, "I know you elected me to lower
taxes but the economy has been hit by international
factors beyond the government's control. Therefore, although I cannot cut your taxes this year I will
do everything in my power to avoid increasing your tax burden." Under a
PRG system, as long as a
representative is transparent and accountable for every decision, the public
will generally accept (but not necessarily like) every decision.
Another common
misunderstanding about PRG is "who" participates. As will be outlined
below, there are various levels of participation. At all of these levels,
participation refers to the actions of individual citizens. Nevertheless, at two
critical levels, policy input and policy oversight, participation is often a group
activity managed under the umbrella of a business, professional, or civic group. One of
the major faults of the RG system is
that as it becomes more corrupt and prone to abuse of power, only those
individuals or groups with wealth and power are able to influence
decision-making. Too often, they literally buy the decision they want from
officials. The merit of the PRO system is that it provides an equal opportunity
for any individual
or group, regardless of wealth or influence, to participate in decision-making,
as well as make it more difficult for anyone to buy a decision.
Major critics of the PRG system often point to
"those meddling NGOs" trying to influence a decision. In reality,
there is no difference between an individual lobbyist or a lobby group
representing a business interest and one claiming to represent a civic interest. For example, an
electrical power lobby fighting to build a new power plant is no different than an
environmental NGO fighting to ensure the
proposed plant does not adversely impact the local environment. Too often the critics have no problems being
wined-and-dined by wealthy and
influential lobbyists representing the construction of a power plant but they will not even listen to the
arguments of the environmentalists.
Indeed, they would argue that the environmental activists only represent themselves and not the community or the public interest. Who then does the power plant
lobbyist represent?
The fact is, not everyone is going to be
concerned with every decision being made. The typical citizen usually only participates
when he or she is very knowledgeable about the issue in question or will be directly impacted by the issue. Again, this
is no different than the typical business
lobby. The folks operating a power plant could care less about participating in a hearing concerning
the construction of an art museum-unless the museum was to be built at
the site of their power plant. Similarly the
artists who are demanding Governor Samak hold hearings about the new modern art museum are not the same people that are protesting in Hin Khrut.
The Five Levels of
Participation
The fundamental
element of a PRG system is participation. There are five basic levels of participation
necessary for effective participatory
representative governance. These are: cognizance; elections; input into public policy formulation and selection; oversight
of public policy implementation; and hands-on, partisan involvement.
Each of these levels represents a
progressively more complex type of participation, and therefore each successive
level is more difficult for a nation to
practice. Moreover, there are indicators which suggest solid practice at one level may be a precondition for successful achievement of the next level of
participation. Nevertheless, a
nation should endeavor toward excellence in all five levels at the same time. A polity that attempts to
sequence the levels will ultimately
retard the development of participation.
The precondition for
effective participation is citizen cognizance of their right to participate.
Few citizens will attempt to participate in their government unless they are
aware that they have the authority to do so. Thailand's 1997 Constitution mandates
such authority to citizens yet the vast majority remain unaware of their rights to participate in
various ways and at diverse levels. Thai citizens do not know how to be
informed participants in public policy and politics because they were
never provided an opportunity to learn. At the same time, few politicians, bureaucrats, or local
administrators understand the implications
of public participation. Moreover, they must change their fundamental values and attitudes toward the concept of public administration. Officials must
forfeit their attitude of command
and control for one of facilitation. For example, the Thai legal term for
"safeguarding the public interest" is khumkhrong satharanaprayot. While khumkhrong may translate as "to
protect", every school child
knows the root word khwn means "to control". Officials need to learn to raksa, "to
take care of rather than khum. The
long-term solution to this double dilemma is a restructuring of the school curriculum and the decentralization of
administration to local communities.
In the interim, it is incumbent on the government to
provide
training to both citizens and officials and to demonstrate its support for public participation through best
practices.
Free and fair
elections constitute the most fundamental form of public participation. All
governments, with the exception of the most authoritarian, allow their citizens to vote. It
is also the fundamental building block for all other forms of participation
because unless a nation has a strong electoral system, its citizens will not be offered
the opportunity
to engage in higher levels of participation. Although elections are fundamental,
no matter how free and fair an election might be, citizen selection of their representatives from a list
of candidates proposed by either the
government or contending political parties is insufficient in itself to secure
democratic governance, and typically
leads to the dangers inherent in representative governance. For most of the past 70 years, for example, Thai
citizens have had the right to vote
but elections did not translate into democratic governance because citizens had little control over their representatives
or the bureaucracy which made decisions on their behalf.
As a result of the
government focus on elections, rather than other levels of participation, Thailand
witnessed the evolution of a supply-driven government in which the political and
administrative elite supplied institutions and services which were not necessarily demanded by, nor
designed to serve the public. It must be acknowledged that many of these projects did
cumulatively serve to build the Thai nation, as well as reduce poverty levels
and create new centers of wealth. At the same time, however, they were an excellent source of graft that
fueled the continued development of a bureaucratic polity accountable only to
itself. Secondly, in many cases these projects destroyed the local
environment, displaced communities, and promoted the destruction of traditional
Thai social and family values in the name of "development".
To prevent these
problems, it is necessary for citizens to participate at a more complex level than simply
casting a ballot. Specifically, they need to exercise their right to participate in a process by which
public concerns, needs, and values are incorporated
into the government's decision-making
process. This must be a process in which the public is heard before a decision
has been made, and in which citizens have a viable opportunity to influence the decision from the
beginning to the end of the process. The purpose of this level of participation is to inform
the public, get the public's reactions
regarding proposed actions or policies, and engage the public in problem solving to design the best
solution for everyone. A solution or
decision made through this manner generally will be seen as legitimate when it is perceived by citizens
that the process was fair, open, and democratic.
Such public participation has a number of benefits. These include
improving the quality of decisions by
anticipating public concerns and attitudes, and thereby offering governments
the opportunity to use consensus building to avoid confrontations. That is, when
properly used,
it is a method to avoid conflict. It should not be viewed, however, as a method
for resolving a conflict that has arisen over a project that is nearing completion, or
that was completed a number of years ago. Participation in public policy design and
implementation also helps to minimize costs and delays while increasing the ease of implementation by
building credibility and legitimacy. Just as important, participation supports
development of public expertise and creativity while training future leaders.
Public participation
in the selection and design of public policies and projects does not guarantee, however, that policies or
projects will be faithfully implemented. A fourth level of participation is required to promote compliance by officials with
the public will. This level is most
often referred to as oversight. Holding officials accountable is perhaps the most difficult level of
participation for the ordinary citizen because it can be the most dangerous.
Therefore, it is most effectively pursued by civil society organizations that
use their numbers to protect their individual members.
There are only three
principle reasons why an official is not faithfully implementing a public policy or project:
the official is incompetent, lazy, or pursuing personal interests rather than public interests.
Typically, the official striving for personal interests will use
every tactic available within their power to
prevent exposure by citizens exercising their constitutional right of
oversight. The most aggressive use murder to stop oversight, although there are
hundreds of
less violent ways of intimidating citizens. Moreover, some citizens are
themselves corrupt and will accept a handsome financial reward to curb their
oversight.
The best way to
address this problem is to remove from office those officials who, for whatever reason, refuse to
implement the public will. The question is
who will replace them. It is here that the fifth level of participation is important. It is a level which is
limited to very few citizens who
believe they can make a difference by becoming
part of the partisan political process by seeking election to office. The problem is, if a system does not have
healthy public participation at the
input and oversight levels, there is a high degree of probability that local politics is controlled by
one family or those associated with
an influential patron/client clique. It is therefore difficult for the
average citizen to displace these influential people from office due to their power over the system. Moreover, it is participation in local public policy debate which
earns an individual a reputation in the community; such an individual does not
have to tell voters what his or her views and policies are but rather simply
remind citizens of where he or she
stands on issues of importance to the community
based on their record.
Thailand's new
constitution has established a wide range of reforms to promote all five levels
of public participation. None of these reforms is working perfectly and no
one should expect them to because in the world of political reality change takes
time. The reforms
have, however, set in motion some favorable trends. For example, new electoral
laws are forcing political parties to focus more on policies rather than
personalities. They are also making it easier for someone with limited
resources to contest and win an election. During the last general election, for
example, some very influential families were soundly defeated at the polls while a
number of new faces emerged on the national political scene. The new
National Counter Corruption Commission Act and conflict of interest laws will
establisha trendfor theexpeditiousremovalof self-interested officials from
office, as well as the incompetent and lazy.
Participation and
Public Hearings
For opponents of
constitutional reformthe proponents of the status #«o-perhaps the most irksome
reform is the requirement that officials facilitate citizen participation in public
policy formulation, and that officials recognize the right of citizens to
overrule policies designed by the government and bureaucracy without prior citizen consultation. As
constitutionally-mandated administrative and fiscal decentralization proceed, more citizens
will seek to be included in local policies
which have a direct and immediate impact on their families. This will
serve as a direct challenge to the wealth, power, and face of provincial power brokers and godfathers who have grown accustomed to imposing their will on local
policies and engaging in corrupt
practices with impunity in order to serve their own self-interests rather than the general good of the community.
Central to long-term reconciliation of this conflict, which will be the source
of numerous human rights violations,
will be vigorous central government
support for public participation in local governance and the political will to rein-in errant feudal
lords.
Powerful business and
state enterprise interests, that may champion constitutional reforms, are also likely to find public participation burdensome and irritating. For the
last half century, lobbyists for the
interests of this community have held a monopoly on public participation in
public policy decision-making. These interests must now compete on an equal footing with lobbying by a vast array of public interest groups including environmental
NGOs, public health NGOs, human
rights NGOs, and numerous community groups specifically drawn together
to contest against a specific policy or project
promoted by a business or a state enterprise.
There are two
standard responses from a business community unwilling to share public policy
participation with members of the public. The first option is to create their
own community group or
NGO to counter those resisting a proposed
project. In this public relations war, the business interest points to community
support for their project as evidenced
by the existence of the civic group. Unfortunately, this tactic too often
strains the social fabric of a community
setting even brother against brother and leads to violence. Such tactics, such
companies, must be shamed and condemned by the wider community. The second option is a SLAPP, or Strategic Lawsuit Against Public Participation. Interests
use SLAPP to divert the attention and
resources of an opponent, as well as sap their emotional and physical energy, by filing frivolous lawsuits to harass and to intimidate. The best defense against the
SLAPP is a counter-SLAPP; however, Thai courts do not have an exemplary record
when it comes to charges of abuse of
process and harassment against wealthy,
influential defendants.
A critical element
of participation in policy formulation, and a key indicator of government support
for public participation, is the public hearing process. Hearings, for the
first time enshrined as a constitutional right, are unfortunately governed by 1996
legislation which debases the process to a public relations exercise controlled
by the
Office of the Prime Minister, with a narrow time-frame and devoid of all
consensus building and conflict avoidance characteristics. Over the past few years
many have criticized public hearings as an ineffective tool because they have failed
to resolve disputes between local communities and the state. Indeed, in many
cases, hearings have led to riots or to long-term protests outside Government House.
Critics of public hearings point to the Yadda Gas Pipeline Project, the
Thai-Malaysian Gas Project, the Pak Mool Dam, the Kaeng Sua Ten Dam, the Prachuab Khiri Khan Power
Stations and the Klong Daan Waste Treatment
Plant as proof public hearings do
not work.
These critics are 100%
wrong because not one of these controversial projects is a demonstration of the failure
of the public hearing process. They are 100% wrong due to the fact that no
public hearings were ever
held for any of these projects. They are 100% wrong
because they believe the public relations exercises conducted
under the 1996 law on public hearings constituted public
hearings. The 1996 law was invoked in each of
these situations to address public
objections to a project already under implementation, if not completed. The 1996 law has proven to be a
failure but the 1996 law, in spite of its name and intent, is not about public
hearings.
Public hearings are a
process through which the public is heard before a decision has been made and
in which citizens have a viable opportunity to influence the decision from
the beginning to the end of the process. The purpose of hearings is to inform
the public, get the public's reactions regarding proposed actions or policies,
and engage the public in problem solving to design the best solution for everyone. Stated in another
way, public hearings work for proposed projects; they do not work to resolve disputes
over decisions already made and implemented. Other mechanisms must be used to
resolve disputes like the Pak Mool Dam and the Thai-Malaysian Gas Project.
Thailand may need to draft two laws: a Public Hearings Act to specify the procedures for all
new, proposed government decisions, and a second law to specify procedures for
addressing disagreements with past government decisions which did not have
public hearings. A single law cannot address these two very different types of
situations.
In drafting the new
Public Hearings Act there are several critical issues that must be considered if the
law is to be effective. These issues include: multiple formats for hearings, a
comprehensive definition of hearings, hearings which address the big picture, hearings as a
democratic process, and hearings which focus on analysis of the facts.
First, the new act must
recognize that there are many different formats for public hearings. It is therefore
important to avoid proscribing specific procedures which would preclude the flexibility to
conduct alternate formats which might be more appropriate for a specific policy or
project. Indeed, public hearings do not always have to be formal
discussions in a conference room, community center, or school gymnasium.
Hearings are a process and therefore they merely need to be a forum for discussing
policy options. In a nation as fortunate as Thailand to have a free, vibrant, and
independent media,
the media itself can be part of the public
hearing process. For example, shortly after Samak Sundornvej was elected
Governor of Bangkok, he proposed that the Dusit Zoo be moved from its location near Parliament. That
zoo is not going to be moved during Samak's tenure as Governor because within the first
week of his announcement, the media had reported every significant criticism of the
move. The media had served as a public hearing mechanism to inform Samak that
there was limited citizen support for his proposal and Samak backed
off. It is very significant to note that Samak had not made a decision
to move the zoo, he had signed no papers ordering such a move, he merely announced
his conviction that the zoo should be moved. Public opinion polls are another
example of an informal hearings mechanism which enables officials to gauge citizen
reactions to government initiatives.
A second critical issue in drafting a
new Public Hearings Act is to ensure that it is comprehensive in its definition.
Section 59 of the constitution requires public hearings for any project or
activity which may affect the quality of the environment, health, and sanitary
conditions, the quality of life, or any other material interests of a citizen or community.
The problem is there are two contenting interpretations of this article. The
Srithanonchai believe hearings are limited to projects or activities of a State
agency, State enterprise, or local government organization. That is, Section 59 is not
applicable to private sector projects or activities. Under a common law interpretation,
"any project or activity" means precisely "any project or activity".
This is because at some point every project or activity of the private sector
requires compliance with relevant laws protecting the community and
individuals, as well as the concurrence of one or more government
agencies.
To illustrate this
point, take the hypothetical example of a pig farm. Suppose an entrepreneur bought
the property next to the Jomtian Ambassador Hotel on a beach south of Pattaya. And
suppose he
decided to build a pig farm to grow thousands of pigs for sale in the Pattaya market.
To the average person, it is obvious that this pig farm is going to smell and
it is going to pollute the beach out in front
of the hotel. The question is, do the owners
of the Jomtian, indeed, do all of the residents in the area, have the right to
demand a public hearing before
the pig farm is built? Under the Srithanonchai interpretation, the answer is sorry, this is a private sector action.
Under the common sense interpretation, the answer is of course because some government agency is going to have to
provide some type of zoning approval
or a license to operate. Moreover, it is an activity which will affect the quality of the environment, health and sanitary conditions, the quality of life, and
other material interests of the
residents and guests of the community.
A third important
element of a viable public hearing law is that it ensures hearings
focus on primary issues rather than a series of interdependent secondary issues. That
is, an effective law must not limit discussions to a specific activity or project when
that activity or project is actually just one element of a much more
comprehensive development program. The Thai-Malaysian Gas Project is a very good example of this
problem. The alleged hearings on this activity have been limited to
discussion of the gas pipeline. However, the emergence of a pipeline from the ocean is not really the
ultimate concern of protesters. Their real
concern is the development of industrial
estates that will be built in the immediate region to take advantage of the gas, and the impact such
industrial development may have on the local environment and their
livelihoods. An effective public hearing law
would force organizers in Songkhla to have hearings on the industrial development plan as a whole, rather than
focusing on just one element.
Fourth, an effective
public hearing law should promote a transparent, accountable, independent
process. Unless citizens perceive the process to be totally democratic, the
majority will never accept the recommendations arising from a hearing, and
the hand of the minority will be strengthened to continue to battle the recommendations and
subsequent decisions. That is, unless the process is democratic, a hearing will promote rather than reduce conflict. It will be a challenge for Thailand to
ensure hearings are democratic
because it will be necessary for civil servants, who
normally organize hearings, to adjust their
attitude toward the public and rebuild their reputation for honesty and
integrity. In the interim, those who appoint individuals to organize a hearing must
maintain high standards in
their selection process to ensure that any official with a conflict of interest is not involved with the hearing. This too,
of course, will be a challenge
because of the Thai tradition of granting accused officials with the benefit of
the doubt. That is, unless there is documented
proof of conflict of interest, an official can still be appointed in
spite of allegations. While this is an admirable and necessary philosophy in a court of law, public hearings are not a court of law but rather a consensus building mechanism
that requires a different set of rules. One of those rules is that the
mere hint of a conflict of interest requires
the removal of an official in question in order to maintain the integrity of the process.
Finally, a good
public hearing law is one which will encourage analysis of the facts and promote
decisions premised on the merits of an activity or project. This means that
citizens and local communities must have equal access to information and
technical expertise related to the activity or project. In alleged hearings held in
Thailand over the past several years, the supporters of a project have typically arrived
with a bevy of lawyers, scientists, technical experts, and government officials who submit
reams of technical studies to support their position. Too often villagers arrive, with or
without the moral support of activist NGOs, armed with arguments premised on
social justice, fairness, and many tears. Unfortunately, without technical data in support of their
arguments, they lose the debate. In the United States there are literally
thousands of interest group organizations (NGOs) and professional associations who are
able to offer their services to communities to challenge the data provided by
project supporters and to develop alternatives. Since Thailand is not yet at
this stage of civil society development, the hearings law may have to
provide for the possibility of public financial support to enable communities to secure technical expertise
on their behalf.
Conclusion
Thailand, as a
nation, faces three fundamental problems as it attempts to promote public participation. First, Thai
citizens don't know how to be informed participants
in public policy and politics-they
were never provided the opportunity to learn. The previous system not only discouraged public participation,
it most cases it prevented
participation with the exception of elections. With a centralized, top-down approach to almost all
decisions, whether at the national,
provincial, or local level, officials made it clear citizens were to be passive participants. Do not ask
questions. Second, many bureaucrats
and local power brokers do not wish to loose the power and influence they have built over the past
decades. Not only is it in their
interests to block political reform, they are certainly not accustomed to being questioned by citizens. As
citizens ask more questions during
this period of transition, there should be no surprise that there will be a significant increase in human
rights abuses in provincial areas.
Third, if citizens have had little experience with participation, few
reform-oriented politicians, bureaucrats, or local administrators-the good guys-understand what
public participation means. Their failure to implement a comprehensive
and effective Public Hearings Act will
preclude citizens from full participation and condemn Thailand to
continue a history of civic conflict over both new mega-projects and community development projects.
In view of these
three problems, the next critical step in the Thai political reform
process is to assist Thai citizens to learn how to become active,
informed participants in their political system; and to assist politicians,
bureaucrats and local administrators to learn how to properly involve
citizens in public policy decision-making. Essential to this process is a
common understanding and recognition of human dignity, rights, equality and duty
coupled with a critical awareness of the political process, wherein citizens
view themselves as important actors and not simply as passive observers. In a
nutshell, the key issue in securing the political reforms of the 1997 Constitution
is to determine
how to change citizen perceptions of their position in society from one of
powerlessness, to a realization of empowerment
with the ability to analyze the
systemic roots of a problem and the capacity to take the initiative for action to
resolve the problem. Equally critical is to determine how to change government
perceptions of best practices
in public participation from one of essentially public relations required by
law to a realization of the benefits of a
participatory approach to national development.